Korean Studies

Internet Discussion List

KOREAN STUDIES REVIEW


Troubled Tiger: Businessmen, Bureaucrats, and Generals in South Korea, by Mark L. Clifford. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe, 1998. (ISBN 0-7656-0140-0 cloth; 0-7656-0141-9 paper). 373 pp.

Reviewed by Timothy C. Lim
California State University, Los Angeles

[This review first appeared in
Acta Koreana, 1 (1998): 143-147]

Asia's recent economic difficulties- which can be traced back to the early 1990s, when Japan first slipped into a still on-going recession- have led an increasing number of observers to conclude that the "Asian Miracle" has run its course. Indeed, many argue that most of the region's economies have not merely run out of gas, but are facing the prospect of serious and long-term economic decline. Not surprisingly, there is also a general consensus on the basic cause of Asia's apparent downfall, namely, an excessive reliance on an authoritarian, bureaucratic and state-controlled approach to capitalist development. The logic here is simple: pervasive state involvement in the economy, which at one point may have served a useful purpose, has become dysfunctional in the more complex, competitive and globalized economic environment of today. The main problem, of course, is that state involvement encourages corruption and inefficiency- the two banes of a smoothly functioning and productive capitalist market economy. Without dramatic change, most of Asia's economies, according to these observers, are almost certainly doomed. In short, the very same systems that created the basis for Asia's economic success in the past are now said to be the fundamental source of the region's current problems.

Mark Clifford's Troubled Tiger: Businessmen, Bureaucrats, and Generals in South Korea falls squarely into this new mode of thinking. In fact, Clifford's book places South Korea at the top of an unenviable list of inflexible, slow-moving and seriously endangered "high-cost, low-efficiency" economies in Asia. In this respect, Clifford- who was a correspondent for the Far Eastern Economic Review from 1987 to 1992 and who now works as the Asia Correspondent for Businessweek - seems particularly prescient: Troubled Tiger was originally published well before the country's recent string of economic disasters, including the failure of two large business groups (Kia and Hanbo) and the still-current and quite serious financial crisis. The ability to "predict" a future crisis, however, is not the main objective of Clifford's book. Instead, in Troubled Tiger, the author's intention is to "to sketch out a more nuanced picture of one of the world's most extraordinary economies than that which appears in either popular or academic accounts" (xi). More specifically, Clifford wants to focus on the relationship between authoritarian politics and rapid economic growth; he is particularly interested in exploring the "often ignored or misunderstood tensions between government and business, and within the government itself ..." (5). To put it simply, Clifford wants to takes us deeper inside the "Korean miracle." To a significant degree, the author carries through on this promise, although, as I will discuss below, Clifford's work is far from perfect.

Troubled Tiger begins with an extremely broad outline of the social, cultural and historical context of South Korea's economic and political development. Running through roughly 2,000 years of history in a mere 15 pages, Clifford quickly gets to the meat of his argument in chapter 3, where he begins his discussion of Park Chung Hee, the man whom most credit with creating the basis for South Korea's phenomenal record of economic growth. Clifford, in fact, does little to dispel the notion that Park was the essential (although, not sole) ingredient in South Korea's economic rise. Indeed, the author attributes much of South Korea's early success to the sheer "force of Park's personality" (67). In this regard, Clifford's chapters on the Park era (which accounts for roughly one-third of his book) break little or no new ground, although his extensive interviews with political and economic elites do give us a valuable "insider" perspective. We find out, for example, that despite Park's strong personality and genuine commitment to national development, he could be easily manipulated by appeals to his ego. According to an interview with Kim Mahn Je (who headed the Korea Development Institute in the 1970s), Park was more likely to approve projects when he was led to believe that ideas proposed by others were his own (59).

Clifford's interviews, however, reveal something far more interesting and valuable than such tidbits of insider information: they also show the relatively high level of bureaucratic infighting and intra-governmental conflict that went on during the Park era - something that has generally been ignored in the English-language literature on Korean development. In this regard, Clifford certainly does what he sets out to do. Another often-ignored aspect of South Korea's political economy is the issue of corruption. But, in Troubled Tiger, corruption takes center stage. Indeed, Clifford goes to great lengths to demonstrate that corruption was part-and-parcel of Korea's political and economic development, even during the Park era. As he succinctly puts it, "... the system was at its heart corrupt." This meant too, that virtually everyone in South Korea with any degree of political or economic power was (and is) vulnerable to charges of corruption, which helps to explain why the country is besieged by scandals and purges almost every time a new leader comes into office. In fact, the author spends a great deal of time discussing details of the "anti-corruption" campaigns carried out by every new regime in South Korea, from Park to Kim Young Sam. Clifford even suggests that Park was not as squeaky clean as he is often portrayed: after his death in 1979, about half a million dollars was found in his personal office safe - curiously, though, the author defends Park by noting that "... at least most of the money stayed in Korea (93).

In general, Clifford's focus on corruption provides a much needed and worthwhile corrective to the hundreds of studies that have portrayed the South Korean state (especially under Park) as a paragon of developmentalism. Clifford does a particularly good job of showing the deep-seated institutional/structural basis of corruption in Korean society. It is disappointing, then, that the author seems to take for granted the notion that corruption in South Korea was primarily, if not wholly, a reflection of unchallengeable state power. This points to a more serious problem in Troubled Tiger: like most people who have written about South Korean development, Clifford largely disregards the possibility that the private sector played an autonomous and proactive role in charting South Korea's developmental course. To be sure, Clifford recognizes the importance of Korea's primary economic agents - the chaebol - but only as relatively passive vehicles for state policy, particularly during the Park years. Clifford, for example, simply asserts that "Park incorporated the private sector into the state" (41); later, while acknowledging that the relationship between business leaders and President Park was "ambiguous," the author nonetheless supports the claim that Park "had them trembling with fear", and could "crush them like insects" (107).

In this respect, Clifford beats a tired refrain, albeit with a few new verses. This is all the more disappointing because the author, at times, clearly recognizes the potentially reciprocal (rather than one-way) nature of state-business relations in Korea. In his chapter on Korea's "Big Push" into heavy and chemical industries, for example, Clifford points out that Park "... needed the economic growth that only business could provide, and businessmen needed the business licenses and access to cheap loans that only the government could grant" (114). On this point, it is important to remember that entrepreneurial and managerial skills were in extremely short supply in South Korea for several decades following liberation. In other words, entrepreneurial/managerial ability was as scarce a resource in South Korea as was (financial) capital; yet, neither could thrive without the other. This meant that, while Park could "crush" a few insectival chaebol on an individual basis, he could not threaten capital as a class. It is, I believe, critical to appreciate the mutually constitutive nature of state-capital relations in South Korea, not only because it paints a more accurate picture of what really happened, but because it provides us with a far better basis for understanding the complex and problematic process of capitalist development in a late developing economy.

Take for example the critical issue of exports. Clifford and others have noted that Park and the members of his "revolutionary council" were so pessimistic about the prospect of selling goods abroad that they deleted the section on exports in the First Five-Year Plan (54). Clifford also notes, however, that Lee Byung Chull (founder of the Samsung Group, one of Korea's largest chaebol), "reputedly was influential in pushing for government support of exports" (ibid.). Clifford, though, does not ask why Lee was so interested in securing export subsidies. If he had, he would have discovered that Lee - like many of his business cohorts - was desperately in need of foreign exchange to purchase raw materials from abroad (Lee's main business lines at the time - sugar, flour and woolen textiles -were all 100 percent dependent on imported raw goods). From this perspective, one can argue that Lee used the government to significantly further his own economic interests. Later, of course, Park used export targets as a way to enforce "discipline" on the private sector. But, this is precisely the point: Lee's entrepreneurial motives put in motion a dynamic that allowed both the state and business to achieve their goals, although not necessarily in the manner both intended. Clifford, in fact, agrees: very early in his book, he argues that the statist approach was successful in stimulating economic growth only because it went hand in hand with "fierce competition" made possible by Korea's intimate involvement in export markets (6). Certainly, neither the state nor big business anticipated that export-led development would create the basis for intense competition, and that this competition would ensure the relatively efficient and productive use of scarce resources.

The second half of Clifford's book is devoted to an examination of the regimes of Chun Doo Hwan, Roh Tae Woo, and Kim Young Sam (I should point out, though, that Clifford's book is not strictly chronological). In these chapters, Clifford adopts a subtle change in tone: whereas his earlier chapters on Park are alternately laudatory and reproachful, his latter chapters are more uniformly critical, even of the economic bureaucracy. Thus, the same bureaucrats that Clifford praised as the "brains" and "hands" of economic policy during the Park era (48-9), had become, by the mid-1980s, out-of-touch "mandarins," who had little practical knowledge of or interest in the real workings of the economy (247). Despite the increasingly detached nature of the economic bureaucracy, the economy continued to grow. Indeed, Clifford points out that, between 1985 and 1988, Korean exports doubled and the country moved into the ranks of the top twelve trading nations in the world.

Not surprisingly, though, Clifford gives the government little credit for bringing about this tremendous spurt of growth in the 1980s. Instead, he attributes the country's export success to a particularly favorable set of international conditions and - more importantly - to far-sighted planning by the private sector. Clifford almost does an about face here: in a curious chapter on the Korean automobile industry, the author implies that the development of this sector was due primarily to the entrepreneurial efforts and vision of men like Chung Ju Yung (founder of Hyundai), rather than to the planning and support of the government. Clifford even asserts that in the struggle for control of the auto industry, "the company [Hyundai] kept what mattered most - its independence" (257). Although Clifford is referring to events that occurred during the Chun years, it is still difficult to reconcile the author's newfound appreciation of private sector autonomy with his earlier assertions of near-total subservience. (On this point, I might also note that Hyundai's automobile company generally pursued its own path even during the Park years.) In general, though, Clifford remains fairly consistent. After all, the primary objective of the second half of Troubled Tiger is to show how once-successful policies become dysfunctional, both in economic and political terms. And, for the most part, he does a good job of this.

Overall, in reading Clifford's perspective on South Korea's political economy, one is treated to a fairly balanced, sometimes surprising, and always easy to read account of a complex story. For these reasons, however, I was particularly unhappy to see Clifford slip into a stereotypical and somewhat offensive (if not racist) mode in the last few chapters of his book, where he discusses the difficulties Korea has faced, and will continue to face, as it moves from the status of a Third World country to a "developed" nation. In these chapters, Clifford seems primarily concerned with showing that Korea and Koreans have a long way to go before they will be ready to "join the Big Leagues" - which to Clifford, seems to mean accepting liberal economic policies. For example, in alluding to a conflict over the importation of Florida grapefruits, Clifford refers to the Korean press as "hysterical," "conspiratorial," and "xenophobic" (297). He then argues that Korean resistance to a fully liberalized agricultural market is little more than an irrational and infantile demand for "affirmative action" (298). In almost the same breath, Clifford turns his attention to Koreans more generally: he notes that, with regard to bilateral trade, US officials are "unhappy with the cocksure attitude of Koreans and their often adolescent assertions of national pride" (italics added, 298). Clifford himself repeats this theme in chapter 24, when accuses Korean authorities of engaging in "juvenile tactics" to discourage imports (337). In his zeal to stereotype Koreans, Clifford even engages in a bit of oxymoronic foolishness - he asserts, for example, that "Koreans too often have a greediness, a sense of atomistic individualism that makes common cause only with others with whom one has an existing connection, such as the family, schoolmates, or coworkers" (342). How one can be atomistically individualist and oriented toward larger social groups at the same time is certainly beyond me.

It is worth reiterating that all of Clifford's denunciations are based on the unwillingness of Koreans to immediately embrace a policy of full liberalization. In other words, because Koreans, in general, are afraid of the risks posed by a sudden opening of their economy, Clifford feels justified in condemning them as infantile, xenophobic, hysterical, and untrusting. One might argue, instead, that Clifford's unwillingness to acknowledge the social cost associated with "liberalization" is the real problem. One could also argue that Clifford's condemnation of Korea is extremely unfair: after all, few countries in history - including the United States - have readily freed themselves of neo-mercantilist practices as they moved from developing to developed status. Indeed, even advanced industrial democracies have recurrent problems regarding "free trade" and open borders - witness the hysterical backlash against Mexican immigrants in the United States. In addition, can one forget the sledgehammering of Japanese imported cars in the 1980s by American autoworkers? Was this the "mature" response to liberalization that Clifford implies the West has taken?

None of this is to say that Koreans should avoid liberalizing their economy; rather, it is to say that Clifford's "hysterical" rhetoric is not an appropriate or particularly constructive way to deal with the issue. Despite these misgivings, I still believe that Troubled Tiger is a useful, informative, and even important book. It should, however, be read with caution and with the understanding that Clifford's perspective is deeply colored by a neo-liberal and distinctly Anglo-American bias, which the author neither questions nor acknowledges.


Citation:
Lim, Timothy C. 1998
Review of Mark L. Clifford, Troubled Tiger: Businessmen, Bureaucrats, and Generals in South Korea (1998)
Korean Studies Review 1998, no. 8
Electronic file: http://koreanstudies.com/ks/ksr/ksr98-08.htm
[This review first appeared in Acta Koreana, 1 (1998): 143-147]
Return to Index of Reviews

Return to Entry Page